OIL: the final countdown, the technical view
Mid Atlantic Renewable Energy Initiative
The final countdown II The IPCC and Conclusion: the Elephant in the Room Essays:
![]()
Paypal & Credit CardsFind us on: orkut | Geopolitical Disruptions #1: Theory of Disruptions to Oil & Resource SupplyPosted by jeffvail on August 14, 2008 - 10:17am The peak and gradual decline in world oil production is beginning to spawn a set of geopolitical positive-feedback-loops that seem likely to exacerbate depletion and accelerate the effective rate of decline of world oil production. Rather than isolated incidents, these geopolitical feedback loops are the direct result of geological peaking in oil production. Unlike geologically driven peaking, however, the effective rate of decline caused by geopolitical feedback loops has the potential to continually accelerate. This post will lay out a theory to better understand the impact of this system of geopolitical phenomena.
I've discussed the impact of various types of geopolitical disruptions to oil production previously at The Oil Drum. One of these geopolitical phenomena, the Export Land Model (ELM), has been well developed by TOD members Westexas and Khebab (see their Iron Triangle post and Wikipedia article). While I think that ELM is already proving to be the most significant of the geopolitical factors--especially in the earlier phases of peak oil--I think that it is important to place ELM into the context of a larger set of geopolitical pheonomena. In part, this is the case because of a similarity between the various geopolitical forces at work. In part, it is because these forces tend to act as alternatives to one another, and their full implications cannot be properly understood in isolation. In this post, the first part in a series, I hope to lay the framework of a theory for better understanding these phenomena, for extrapolating trends, and for predicting their future impact. It is also important to place the problem of geopolitical disruptions in context, and to highlight the danger of dismissing these phenomena as isolated and separate "above ground factors." The next post in this series will review and update the set of geopolitical feedback loops currently in action, looking not only at disruptions to oil production, but also at the larger issue of resource production, including gas, coal, fertilizer, metals, etc. The final post will discuss the interrelationship between the various geopolitical forces at work as well as the potential approaches to "solve" this system of problems. Building a Theory of Geopolitical Disruptions to Resource Supply Since this theory is still very much in formation, I'll proceed by asking a series of questions, followed by my best answer at present. I hope that readers will help to both refine these answers, as well as propose additional questions that must be addressed: 1. Are Geology and Geopolitics Separate? When considering peak oil, it is tempting to look at the issue as a purely a matter of depletion due to geology and production economics. While peak oil certainly begins with the study and understanding of geological depletion, it spawns a set of exacerbating geopolitical factors that are critical to understanding the ultimate scope and impact of peak oil. Some commentators consider "above ground factors" to be separate, stand-alone phenomena that are neither related to nor driven by the geological peaking of oil production. This is a critical mistake. Rather than being merely isolated phenomena, these geopolitical forces are best viewed as phenomena that would not exist but for geological constraints. Without geological constraints on oil production--specifically without geographical constraints on where remaining viable oil reserves are located--oil producers would produce sufficient oil from geopolitically stable locations. In reality, resources are almost always subject to uneven geographical distribution. For economic and political reasons, consuming nations tend to produce domestic supplies first. When consuming nations produce oil in foreign nations, regions with geopolitical stability and stable legal systems to protect property interests are favored, so oil from these countries tends to be produced first. As a result, when the world has produced roughly half of its reserves, and when world production approaches peaking, the majority of remaining reserves (especially the majority of economically viable reserves) tend to be located outside consuming countries in the least geopolitically and legally stable regions. This, roughly, is why "our oil" is increasingly likely to be located "under their sand." As a result, today's increasing geopolitical problems in oil and resource production are a direct result of geological factors combined with picking the low hanging fruit first. If it had made more sense to produce oil from offshore Nigeria, Azerbaijan, or the Arctic first, and save Texas and Alaska oil for later, we would have done that. But because that wasn't what made sense, today's geopolitical problems are a direct result of geography when viewed from a macro perspective. Additionally, this process of explaining why geopolitical problems exist today also demonstrates that it is useful to view geopolitical problems as a global system of phenomena, not as isolated events. 2. Are Geopolitical Disruptions Feedback Loops? It seems that geopolitical forces act as positive feedback loops. I'll detail the feedback inside and between various geopolitical forces in my next post, but for now I'll outline the general concept: 1) global scarcity of oil, energy, or other resources increases the likelihood of disruption to the supply of that resource (for various reasons that I've discussed before and will outline in more detail in the next post in this series); 2) when these disruptions occur, they further increase the global scarcity of the resource, increasing the effect noted in #1 and creating a positive feedback loop.* For that reason, I call this set of exacerbating factors "geopolitical feedback loops" as they are subject to positive feedback both from their own operation and from the rate of geologically-driven depletion. I think that term is appropriate, but admittedly a bit cumbersome--I'll shorten it to "GFL" for now. *Some GFLs may not be positive feedback loops--the Export Land Model, for example, is probably a positive feedback loop to the extent that the drop in net exports from one exporter causes global prices to rise enough to make that exporter's export revenues increase despite the decline in net export volume. However, it would be a negative feedback loop if the rise in domestic consumption due to high export revenues (the system's output) has the result of decreasing export revenues (feeding the system's output back into the system in an inverted manner) and thereby causing a decrease in domestic consumption (acting to re-establish equilibrium). 3. How Does the "Rate" of Disruption from Geopolitics and Geology Compare? There are also critical differences between the rate of geological depletion and the potential rate at which geopolitical disruptions cumulatively impact oil supply rates. Unlike depletion, whereby oil production from a given field or set of fields decreases rapidly after peaking before beginning to "tail off" and decrease more slowly (the black line in the graphic above), geopolitical forces may disrupt production catastrophically, or may disrupt production at a rapidly accelerating rate (the red line in the graphic above). This is not to say that GFLs will have a greater impact than geology--while it is certainly possible that a single geopolitical disruption will dramatically outpace geological depletion over a short time period, geological factors will likely be the main determinant of oil production declines during the initial phases of peak oil. However, depending on our society's ability to mitigate Peak Oil with substitute energy sources and to adapt to a lower energy world, it also seems likely that geopolitical disruptions will eventually overtake depletion as the most significant problem. Because geopolitical disruptions will have a disproportionately greater impact in an environment of increasing oil scarcity, as well as due to factors involved in secondary and tertiary recovery methods, the right half of the global oil production curve will not look like the left--when the impact of GFLs are added to the rate of geological decline, the drop in global oil production may be much faster than generally expected. 4. Along What Timeline Will Geopolitical Disruptions Unfold? Geological forces do not require an actual peak in global oil or energy production to begin to form positive feedback loops--rather, the catalyst for positive feedback is the onset of diminishing marginal returns in investment in energy, where energy begins to become more expensive in relative terms. While global oil and energy supplies may not have peaked, we have almost certainly crossed the threshold of more expensive energy. Also unlike depletion, geopolitical feedback loops may disrupt production in a region that is still far from geological peaking. For this reason, it is reasonable to expect GFLs to increasingly disrupt global oil production alongside an increase in the scarcity of oil, and before an actual peak in global production. Annecdotal evidence supports this view of the the timing of geopolitical disruptions: while some degree of scarcity of oil has coincided with geopolitical disruptions in the past, increasing scarcity over the past decade has coincided with easily observable increases in geopolitical disruptions. While I think the general issue of timing is obvious, one critical unanswered question remains: how fast will geopolitical disruptions impact overall production rates? 5. Will the Aggregate Effect of Geopolitical Disruptions be Smooth or Unpredictably "Bumpy"? Unlike geological depletion, geopolitical disruption is uniquely susceptible to "black swan" events--things that simply cannot be predicted. This is problematic because, unlike geological depletion which can be understood as a slow but compounding process, geopolitical disruptions may appear non-existent, but then suddenly exert a huge toll on global production. This makes predictions of future oil production levels even more uncertain than predictions that account for only geological factors, and increased uncertainty in estimating future oil production makes selecting and mobilizing the necessary political will for various mitigation options more difficult. Some GFLs, such as the Export Land Model, will likely produce fairly smooth and predictable effects. Others, like the increased motivation to target oil production infrastructure, will likely produce relatively smooth aggregate effects, but will be subject to significant and sudden disruptions--for example, if al-Qa'ida successfully destroys the export terminal at Ras Tanura, or if Iran blockaded the Strait of Hormuz. The critical unanswered question here is whether, in aggregate, the impact of GFLs will be predictably smooth (as assumed in the graphic at the top of this post) or unpredictably volatile. 6. Is the System of Geopolitical Feedback Loops Solvable? Because individual geopolitical disruptions can be "solved", there is a tendency to think of them as separate from geological challenges (and thereby a convenient alternate explanation for those who don't like the implications of geological depletion). Additionally, there is a tendency to think that because individual problems are solvable, the system of geopolitical forces can also be solved as a whole (specifically, solved by the same tool-set of security, military force, etc.). In reality, while the occurrence of individual events and geopolitical disruption in individual regions is highly uncertain (and too complex to predict mathematically), the increasing scarcity of oil and other resources caused by geological factors creates an ever increasing catalyst to geopolitical disruption. In the face of geological depletion, geopolitical disruption is not a question of if, but a question of where and how fast. If a single geopolitical disruption--say, a militant group attacking a pipeline--can be solved, why can't the larger system also be solved? In theory, it can, but there are systemic problems to solving the larger system. In general, this is because the "solutions" to the individual problems are actually to overwhelm and repress the root cause locally--something which will become increasingly difficult globally. For example, the Nigerian rebels can, theoretically, be defeated by overwhelming government force, but this does not solve their grievance--that their ethnic group is being oppressed and resources that are rightfully theirs are being appropriated. Rather, it relies on overwhelming military force and expenditure to repress it (and, it should be noted, this "solutions" is being discussed theoretically, as the massive military force and expenditure by Nigeria's government at present is failing miserably to repress rebel attacks on oil infrastructure). It seems, at least to me, far more likely that the world can concentrate resources to temporarily repress geopolitical flare-ups regionally, especially in the earlier phases of peak oil. However, if global resources are spread thin, it is impossible to address every trouble spot simultaneously. Because of this, it seems unlikely that there would be enough pressure at individual points to repress disruptions across the entire system. Finally, while many geopolitical problems can be repressed by favoring one side in a dispute as leverage against the other (the Exploitation Model), it is often not fundamentally possible to actually resolve the issue by making all parties happy (thereby eliminating the root cause of the geopolitical disturbance) because the minimum demands of opposing groups are often mutually exclusive. I've written about this problem of Mutually Exclusive Overlap before, and I think that it makes the global system of geopolitical feedback loops an inevitability. However, while I think that the broader system is not "solvable," I do think that it is possible to buffer their effect, a topic I will discuss in a later post. 7. Is Price the Sole Catalyst of Geopolitical Disruptions? While demand destruction and economic troubles may grant a temporary reprieve from increasing geopolitical tensions (because they may temporarily reduce the underlying catalyst of scarcity), the steady march of resource depletion will eventually catch up and cause geopolitical tensions to escalate again unless a truly economical, scalable substitute for fossil fuels is built out sufficient to negate depletion and accommodate continued economic and population growth. In that sense, if peak oil is not a problem for humanity, neither will we suffer the exacerbating effects of geopolitical feedback loops. However, to the extent that peak oil presents a serious problem, it will be increasingly exacerbated by geopolitics. Additionally, demand destruction is particularly inefficient at buffering these geopolitical feedback loops because the lowest value consumption tends to be "destroyed" first. In a demand destruction scenario, when consumers are forced to reduce consumption out of economic necessity, they will choose to first eliminate the consumption that is least necessary to the maintenance of their quality of life. As a result, as demand destruction gradually decreases consumption, the consumption that remains is, by process of elimination, increasingly inelastic. For this reason, demand destruction actually exacerbates the positive-feedback nature of these geopolitical phenomena. A pipeline bombing, cartel action, or rise in domestic consumption that removes 500,000 barrels of oil per day from the international market exerts far more leverage on a future United States that consumes only 10 million barrels (due to demand destruction) per day of oil than it does on today's United States that consumes roughly 20 million barrels per day. However, if this same future United States only consumes 10 million barrels per day of oil due to the development of economically viable substitutes and voluntary efficiency measures, then this would not be the case. I'll address this point in more detail in my discussion on buffering GFLs in a later post. In general, if scarcity is the underlying catalyst to geopolitical disruptions, I think that price is not the best indicator of that scarcity--rather, price of a barrel of oil as a percentage of purchasing power parity may be more appropriate. 8. Are Geopolitical Feedback Loops "Scale Free"? A scale free system (aka a fractal) is one that exhibits the same behavior at all levels. Do GFLs operate as a scale free system? Assuming that, at a point in the future where total oil production is rapidly declining, there would be a world wide catalyst for geopolitical disruption to oil supplies, would it also be true that a region where oil production is rapidly declining will see a regional catalyst before world supply begins to decline? The answer is still unclear. Mexico, for example, is already well beyond its peak in oil production--ahead of the global process of peaking. Does this mean that internal pressures in Mexico are greater than elsewhere, that the driving forces behind geopolitical feedback loops are greater than elsewhere, or that the attacks on Mexico's gas pipelines can be attributed to GFLs being more advanced in Mexico than elsewhere? We don't know. In theory, it seems reasonable to suggest that a country experiencing the problems with its own early peak may experience greater geopolitical pressures than others, but it is far from clear that this is the case in Mexico where oil export revenues are still rising, and where there are ample alternative explanations for the gas pipeline attacks. Additionally, other countries where production peaked well before global production (e.g. the US, Norway, UK, though arguably not Indonesia) haven't experienced a localized rise in geopolitical tensions. There are many complicating factors (especially when viewing the US and UK and their position on the world stage), but this is a possibility to keep track of as some regions progress past peak before others. 9. How Should Quantitative Data be Integrated in this Model? One criticism of this model of geopolitical feedback loops is, quite understandably, its lack of hard, quantitative data at its base. In one sense, the subject matter is fundamentally less suitable to quantitative, data-driven analysis than the core issue of geological depletion. Some exceptions stand out--the Export Land Model, mentioned above, is a prime example of a geopolitical feedback loop that is well suited to data-driven analysis. Even ELM, however, presents problems for data-driven analysis. For example, when an exporting state that currently subsidizes domestic fuel prices decides to cut that subsidy when export revenues begin to decline, or if a state decides to buy domestic political support by using some of its export revenues to boost subsidies, how do we integrate the impact of this fundamentally political maneuver with the more pure analysis of net export declines? Similarly, it is quite challenging to gather accurate data of nationalist sentiment (and the degree to which this sentiment may lead to violence), the ability to mobilize political will to conserve resources for future generations, the degree to which resources motivated a military "adventure"--all of these demonstrate the challenge of bringing data-driven analysis to inherently "fuzzy" topics. Perhaps the most important question is the degree of importance of data-driven analysis to this topic. Will the quest for mathematical analysis of these topics provide more predictive power for a given amount of effort, or will it create a misleading appearance of accuracy and predictive ability while actually creating faulty conclusions? If quantitative analysis is appropriate here, how, specifically, should it be carried out? This question, in particular, is one where I hope the many TOD readers with experience in this area will weigh in. I plan to begin to introduce some quantitative data in the next post in this series by attempting to tally the amount of production currently shut-in or otherwise disrupted due to the various categories of GFLs around the world. I expect it will be difficult to accurately track this data over time (at least when compared with our ability to track actual oil production), but it seems like the best place to start with quantitative analysis, and may provide some insight into the rate and timing of geopolitical impacts on oil production. 10. Is the Potential for Financial Crash a Geopolitical Feedback Loop? It's purely artificial to separate the financial impact of peak oil from the geopolitical impact--in fact, there are broad areas of overlap between the realm of finance or macroeconomics with geopolitics. How should these issues be integrated into this model, if at all? It is unclear to me whether financial markets are an exacerbating or mitigating factor in the context of broader geopolitical disruptions. In one sense, the financial turmoil caused by high oil prices makes it more difficult to raise capital necessary to exploit new technologies, develop substitutes for oil, and to produce more economically challenging oil reserves. Likewise, price volatility and peak oil combine to exacerbate both financial and geopolitical issues. However, it can also be argued that financial turmoil mitigates the geopolitical problems of peak oil by destroying demand and reducing scarcity (though, as mentioned above, this is a double edged sword because it may increase inelasticity of the remaining demand). I hope that readers can propose the best way to integrate models and predictions of financial turmoil (such as Gail the Actuary's recent financial market predictions) with this model of geopolitical feedback loops. Conclusion I've recently finished the book "We Think" by Charles Leadbeater. This book is an outstanding discussion of the advantages and pitfalls of collaborative innovation. I'm not proposing that the theoretical framework I'm setting forth in this and later posts is in any way gospel truth--it is an initial effort to tackle a very complex system of problems, and certainly needs further development. The Oil Drum is, in many ways, an ideal example of a "we-think" collaborative environment, and I hope that the amazing breadth and depth of knowledge of TOD readers will help to further develop this theory. Developing a better understanding of the impact of a system of geopolitical feedback loops in resource production is a critical first step in both improving our ability to predict future energy and resource supplies, and in understanding how to best act to mitigate resulting problems. Hopefully my answers to the above questions begin to lay out a foundation for a broad theory of geopolitical disruption to resource supply. In the next post I will look at several discrete geopolitical phenomena within this analytical framework, but for now my hope is to start a discussion of the overarching issues raised in this post. Countdown to $200 oil (10) - oil at $115!!Posted by Jerome a Paris on August 10, 2008 - 6:00pm in The Oil Drum: Europe
I have been gently chided on the internets for not doing any Countdown diaries since the oil prices have started going down. While the giddiness and glee demonstrated by many in the traditional media and elsewhere invites little but ridicule, as demonstrated by this graph below, prepared for the Oil Drum, some serious questions have been raised and deserve answers. ![]() So, beyond the semi-glib answer that nothing much has in fact happened in the oil markets in the past month (after all, the recent decline is still smaller, in percentage terms, than several others in the past couple of years), here are a few points worth making. An installment of the Countdown to $200 oil series "It was speculation and the bubble has popped" Many don't agree with my assertion that speculation has little or nothing to do with the run-up in oil prices, and consider that the brutal price increases, followed by just as brutal price decreases, cannot be explained by fairly small changes in supply or demand figures. Let me try to explain again why, in today's conditions, small variations have precisely such consequences. In a market where supply is plentiful, balancing the market will be done by supply adjusting, ie the price will be such that just the required volume of oil is extracted to fulfill demand, and no more. In that case, competition between suppliers plays in full, and the price will the be the marginal cost of supply, is the cost of the most expensive barrel needed to fulfill exactly demand. All cheaper producers will get that same price (and will make a nice profit the cheaper their costs are), and those that are more expensive won't produce. In such circumstances, variations in demand (or new supply coming online) can only cause price to move slowly along the production cost curve, and bigger price movements usually come from "above ground" factors, ie geopolitical crises that include a risk of major disruption of supply. But if you move to a market where supply is fully used to satisfy demand, you enter a whole new world. In that case, if potential demand still increases, there is no supply in the short term to fulfill such demand, and the absolute requirement for physical balance of the market translates (beyond using stocks, which can only be temporary) into a need to destroy demand, ie for some potential users to forego using oil. As we all know, oil is really convenient, and we are all unwilling (and, in many cases, unable) to stop using it. And yet the demand destruction needs to happen. In the short term, that requires prices to go high enough to convince someone to stop using the stuff, either because s/he can't afford it, or because s/he chooses an alternative which is less convenient but cheaper and, at such level of saving, worth the hassle. In such circumstances, short term price movements can and will be quite violent. In fact, any event that disturbs supply, any news that shows that demand was higher than expected, or supply less than hoped, or that suggest that demand will be higher than thought, or supply lower than expected, will push prices up immediately (and the opposite news, down, of course), because thee news translate into a unbalance between supply and demand and a bigger need for demand destruction (conversely, a lower need for such).
In fact, in the past month, these was a succession of news that all went in the same direction. In the same week, Bernanke was extremely bearish on the economy, oil stocks were higher than expected, and talks with Iran happened. Each of these took about 3-4% each from the price of oil, bring the price down by more than $15 in 3 days. And any time this happens, speculators are wrong footed and they need to close out their positions, which usually reinforces temporarily the underlying movement (haha! so there are speculators! And they push prices around! Well, yes, there are speculators - but, for the most part, they follow the market rather than driving it. Any price overshoot is usually temporary. And they do provide valuable services, by bringing in liquidity to prices - and by providing willing counterparties to those that want to buy hedges - you know, like airlines that buy futures or options for their supply over the next few months or quarters at prices to protect themselves - and their fares - from yet higher prices). :: :: One point that needs to be made again is that demand destruction in the US (or even in Europe, where it is hapoening too) is not enough on its own to bring prices down, because it needs to be larger than the supply growth in the rest of the world to limit the requirement for further demand destruction and price rises, given that production is still largely stagnant. And the problem is that demand is not growing just in China and India, thanks to rapid growth, it is also growing massively in oil producing countries themselves (Saudi Arabia, Iran, Russia, Venezuela), which often subsidize gas and which can afford it given that they have a natural hedge against (the subsidy gets bigger when oil prices are higher, ie when their own income is bigger, and the income growth is larger than the subsidy growth for those that export any volumes). In fact, most of the demand destruction happens in price sensitive places, like the poorest oil-importing countries (but they weren't burning much of it anyway), and the rich world (which can still afford oil, but consumes lots of it). But we can't be sure it happens fast enough to actually cause prices to go down because of what's going on in the rest of the world. Anything that encourages demand reduction elsewhere (like lower subsidies) helps to bring prices down, but it's by no means obvious that we've reached price levels that are sufficient to cause overall demand stagnation in the face of flat or quasi-flat production. Oil producers have little or no incentive to boost their production if they expect prices to keep on creeping up (and they can help that trend by, precisely, investing less), and it's not clear what substitutes are available in any meaningful volumes. So, at this point, I'm still happy to continue my "Countdown to $200 oil series" and see no reason why the recent lull in prices would be a sign of a serious trend change in the market. In fact, I'll say again that our energy policies should focus on one thing first and foremost: demand reduction. Any reduction in demand that we manage in excess of what market forces would (precisely) force us to do will get prices down, and will save us a lot of money - and the smartest demand destruction is the permanent kind, that brings savings every month and every year rather than one-offs like giving up a trip. We have to reduce our demand. Let's do it in an organized way rather than a panicked, haphazard, inconsistent way. And that's where government can help, by providing longer term pespective, informing citizens, pushing infrastructure in the relevant direction, and bringing up standards that apply to all equally and guide individual behavior in the right (Energy Smart) direction. Price mechanisms work, but they are brutal, hurt the poor the most, and cause unnecessary disruption to economic activity, and pain to many. And they are fickle, as the current volatility (which, as I explained above, is likely to remain) causes rapidly changing signals which prevent decisions from being taken. How Technology Increases Oil ProductionPosted by Phil Hart on July 17, 2008 - 10:00am in TOD: Australia/New Zealand
How can you double something and still have ten times less than you started with?
![]() The Handil Oil FieldHandil is a giant oil field in the Mahakam Province of Indonesia, discovered in 1974 and still operated by 'TOTAL Exploration and Production Indonesia'. The International Society of Petroleum Engineers had a feature article on 'Reviving the Mature Handil Field' in the January 2008 addition of their Journal of Petroleum Technology [1]. ![]() Figure 1: Location of the Handil Oil Field
API and Sulphur from this Handil Crude Oil Assay Oil RecoveryBefore proceeding, it is important to understand the basic mechanisms of recovering oil from a reservoir:
Primary Recovery is the oil produced by the original reservoir drive energy. The two most important natural reservoir drive mechanisms are Gas Depletion and Water Drive:
It depends highly on the type of reservoir drive, the viscosity of the oil and permeability of the reservoir, but primary recovery produces on average 30-35% of the oil initially in place (OIIP), although it can be as low as 5%. Generally this leaves a considerable amount of oil in the reservoir, so additional recovery techniques may be employed: Secondary Recovery: This involves injecting water into the field through injection wells. It can be initiated before or after the natural reservoir drive has been fully depleted. The aim is to use the water to sweep some of the remaining oil to producing wells. A waterflood can recover anything from 5-50% of the remaining oil in place that would not have been produced using primary recovery alone. The actual amount achieved depends enormously on the properties of the particular field. Tertiary Recovery (Enhanced Oil Recovery): In some cases, where Secondary Recovery still leaves a significant amount of oil in place in the reservoir, enhanced oil recovery may be effective. Enhanced Oil Recovery (EOR) includes thermal, chemical and miscible gas processes - injecting substances into the reservoir that are not naturally found there. Secondary Recovery techniques have been widely used since the early days of the industry. They are already in place in almost all fields where it is necessary or effective. The history of Tertiary recovery also goes back more than half a century. Tertiary Recovery, however, is only effective for a narrow selection of fields and involves substantially higher costs and effort. Lifecycle of a Giant Oil FieldIn their 1986 assessment of the world's 500 "Giant Oil and Gas Fields", Carmalt and St John [3] ranked Handil number 303 with an estimated 800 million barrels of ultimately recoverable oil. We can see that this 20 year-old estimate is very close to the mark in terms of the amount of oil produced with primary and secondary recovery (see Table 2). This should give us increased confidence in the Carmalt and St John estimates for other giant fields, including those in Saudi Arabia and other OPEC countries where current data transparency is inadequate. ![]() Figure 2: Handil Oil Production History
The production profile here presents a common picture of the lifecycle of a giant oil field. Secondary recovery (water injection) is used to maintain an oil production plateau for as long as possible before more significant decline becomes inevitable. After that, owners of the field have to decide whether intensive efforts to study, develop and apply tertiary (enhanced) recovery will recover enough additional oil to make it economically attractive. Mature Field Revitalization
Of the 8 million barrels produced using enhanced recovery mechanisms up to 2002, 6 million was from Phase 1 Lean Gas injection and 2 million from Phase 2 Lean Gas injection. Spurred on by their early success with lean gas injection, TOTAL kicked off a bigger campaign of 'Mature Field Revitalization' in 2003, including the following activities:
The stated costs for LWOs yield a figure of $2 per barrel added as reserves - very economical but the potential is of course very limited (production costs are in addition to this). The more expensive infill wells were used for shallow reservoirs with heavy oil, or multi-lateral wells to target multiple small reservoirs which did not justify single wells previously. The ResultsHopefully it is clear that what is simply described as 'Mature Field Revitalization' comprises many years of technically challenging study and modeling followed by intensive application in the field. For the engineers and geologists involved this was no doubt rewarding work. While all of these activities can be considered the application of 'new technology', only the final step is considered Enhanced Oil Recovery.
For a substantial investment of time, money and effort in the giant Handil oil field, we gain just 10,000 barrels per day of oil production. Yet this case study has appeared in the Journal of Production Technology because it is a prime example of what can be achieved (the two other case studies in the same issue showed only very mediocre gains). While there will be isolated fields that perform better, there will be many more that fail to make the pages of the Journal of Petroleum Technology because they provide far less spectacular returns. In many cases, after intensive appraisal and assessment the schemes never get off the drawing board.
The Impact of TechnologyTOTAL would be pleased if their efforts with the Handil oil field can increase the ultimate amount of oil recovered by even 5% (40 million barrels) compared to primary and secondary recovery alone. A 10% increase in this case looks unlikely. The returns look pretty small when averaged across the world's oil fields, given that only a proportion of them deliver a reward for this kind of effort. While these aspects of 'advanced oil field technology' can increase production from particular oil fields, thereby attractively increasing profits for the owner, they do not significantly alter the picture of global oil resources. ![]() Figure 3: World Oil Discovery and Production The Law of Diminishing ReturnsEconomists seem to have trouble understanding geological and technical limits to oil production, but they should understand the law of diminishing returns (Wikipedia):
In our case we have finite, bounded oil fields. Until the mid 1980s, discovery of new oil fields exceeded our consumption rate, so there was little need to increase recovery from existing fields. As the discovery rate declined, companies had greater motivation to extract more from their existing fields. While at first they found easy gains, in the last decade especially the amount of effort required has climbed and yet the returns are falling: is it any surprise that oil industry inflation is rampant? Oil field reserves may have 'grown' 10-20 per cent since the Carmalt and St John assessment in 1986, but we should not expect the next 20 years to deliver the same gain. Discovery of new fields has tapered off to low levels and the easy pickings for increased recovery have already been had. Unconventional oil sources will yield similarly small returns for extraordinary amounts of effort. The numbers simply do not stack up for oil production continuing to expand for another decade against the decline in large mature conventional oil fields. SummaryHow can you double something and still have ten times less than you started with? In the case of the Handil Oil Field, a concerted campaign to revitalize the field almost doubled production from 12,500 barrels per day in 2003 to 23,000 in 2007. Yet this field had once produced nearly two hundred thousand barrels per day. This is a representative picture of the role of technology and enhanced oil recovery: merely extending the tail end of production in oil fields that are well past their own peak in production. So while the Society of Petroleum Engineers and other optimists tell us that technology and enhanced oil recovery will delay peak oil, a more objective look at the data suggests that production declines are relentless and they are stacking up much faster than incremental technological gains. Contact the Author or download this article as a PDF. Try these tags for other relevant articles at The Oil Drum: References: [1] Denney, D. "Reviving the Mature Handil Field: From Integrated Reservoir Study to Field Application", Journal of Petroleum Technology, Society of Petroleum Engineers, Houston, January 2008. [2] Hyne, Norman J., "Nontechnical Guide to Petroleum Geology, Exploration, Drilling, and Production". PennWell Corporation, Tulsa, Oklahoma, 2001. [3] Carmalt, S. W., and St. John, B. "Giant oil and gas fields," in M.T. Halbouty, ed., Future petroleum Provinces of the World, Memoir, 40, AAPG, Tulsa, Oklahoma, 1986. [4] Mature Kutei Basin of Indonesia: http://www.ccop.or.th/PPM/document/SEM2/Indonesia.pdf Solving the "Enigma" of Reserve GrowthPosted by Khebab on July 16, 2008 - 10:00am
Update: WebHubbleTelescope has posted an updated version of this post here. Many analysts have found this reserve growth behavior both curious and ultimately very important. I know that Khebab and Rembrandt have spent much time on TOD tracking this behavior as it plays an important role in how the peak will play out. Furthermore, I believe that the practice of "back-dating" discoveries based on reserve growth updates has muddied the waters and stalled progress in the basic understanding of the fundamental growth process. Unless we have a good model for the reserve growth dynamics we have to resort to using the heuristics supplied by USGS geologists, including the modified Arrington equation that Khebab has successfully used in the past. I find nothing wrong with using a heuristic and Khebab has really kick-started the "un-back-dating" approach with some excellent results. Still, a heuristic lacks some of the predictive power and room for insight that a fundamental model can provide. The USGS crew have an interesting take on the reserve growth issue. In turns, the geologists working there have labeled fossil fuel (both oil and NG) reserve growth an "enigma" and a "puzzle". For that reason the United States Geological Survey (USGS) considers [this] analysis "arguably the most significant research problem in the field of hydrocarbon resources assessment."I have to admit that it has puzzled me for a while, but then again most of us here don't work at the USGS for 40-hours a week. This post runs though a stochastic analysis that essentially explains how reserve growth can happen. One of the technical issues that the USGS have struggled with respect to their reserve growth analysis involves the use of "censored data". This essentially says that you should take special care of extrapolating data backwards considering you have only a truncated time-series data set of recent vintage. The "sweet spot" for good data basically doesn't exist, with very few values for old data and also very few values for the latest data. Working with such a limited data set, they massaged it the best they could and adequately normalized the fractional yearly growth, but they basically punted after this point and came up with only a heuristic to "explain" the trend. Pragmatically, I've decided to sweep the censoring problems under the rug, since in the long term, complaining about the possibility of statistical shortcomings still won't explain most of the trend, which rises steeply enough to make the cornucopians hopeful for great prospects ahead (listen to any right-wing radio program today for examples of this kind of unbridled optimism). "We must accept finite disappointment, but we must never lose infinite hope." -- Martin Luther King Jr.Yet we still have left a riddle wrapped in a mystery inside an enigma. The actual problem with the half-baked reserve growth analysis has become obscured by the trickiness with using censored data. Wrapped inside, it really stems from a lack of a good value for the initial discovery estimate. Stating it bluntly, pick this number incorrectly and you can get numbers all over the map, with the possibility for some hugely absurd values. To provide a path forward in unwrapping the riddle, I used the generalized Dispersive Discovery Model. In terms of modeling reserve growth, the dispersion generates a tail for accumulating further discoveries after the initial estimate occurs. For constant average growth, the model looks like this:
For the purposes of this analysis, I convert it to a reserve growth
value U(t)
and set T=L/k
to make the math easier to handle later on:
Note
that at time t=0, the discovered amount starts at zero and then the
accumulation reaches some value proportional to L -- what one should
consider as the characteristic depth or volume of the reservoir. It
takes time=T for most of the search to reach this point. The
basic
premise of reserve growth and what USGS geologists such as Attanasi
& Root1 and Verma2 frame their arguments on, has to
do with the reserve growth considered as a multiplicative factor of the initial estimate.
They see numbers that reach a value of nearly 10x after 90 years and
claim (perhaps implicitly) that this has some real physical
significance, almost offering up hope for still-to-come huge reserve
benefits. Figure 1 exaggerates the claim for effect, as I
want to make
you aware that a finite asymptote certainly exists, but it gets
obscured by the data trends commonly reported.![]() ![]() Figure 1: Potential for huge reserve
growth
The contrived swindle of the USGS explanation has to do with exactly when the original estimate becomes available. Conceivably you can make estimates that occur very early in the lifespan of a reservoir, and you will get very low estimates for estimated discovery size. To take it to one extreme, you might find the initial estimate to fill a sewing thimble. Now, if that estimate grows at all, you can get huge apparent reserve growth factors, some fraction approaching infinite in fact. In contrast, you can wait a couple of years and then report the data. The later years' growth factor will proportionately account for much less of an increase. Now if you consider that in other parts of the world, countries report reserves less conservatively then the USA, then the reserve growth factors can vary even more wildly. I used USA oil data from an Attanasi & Root paper1 which you can find a dump of here. Initially, I plotted the data as a fractional yearly growth curve, basically reproducing the trend that A&R report: ![]() Figure 2:
Trend duplicated from the A&R data. The blue '+' symbols
represent
the data and the red curve represents a small-window moving average. To
generate the curve correctly, you must normalize the yearly growth per reservoir, as the reservoir sizes
vary widely.
The key insight to understand the growth factor in terms of the DD model has to do with averaging the initial discovery point over a relatively small window of time starting from t=0. This effectively samples the infinite values of growth against other finite values. The use of the sampling/integration window brings down the potentially infinite (or at least very large) growth factor to something more realistic. The math on this derives easily into an analytic form, and we end up with this function, where A indicates the time integration window: The term on the right of the main divisor assures that the average U_bar starts at 1 for time t=0. Alternatively we can set A to some arbitrary value and skip the integration, which assumes that all initial discovery estimates start at t=A/2. This results in the conceptually simpler:
![]() So what do these numbers mean? Essentially, A=6.6 means that the first discovery estimate on occurs on average 3.3 years after they first made the discovery. This makes intuitive sense because if we make the estimate too early, we end up with the equivalent of a thimble-full of oil. For T=24.6, this means that it takes about 25 years for the majority (i.e. the fast part) of the dispersive search to take place. The rest of the long tail results from the slower dispersion. The curve does eventually reach the asymptote for a cumulative growth factor of 8.5. In terms of a spreadsheet, you can turn the CGF formula into a discrete generating function, with the yearly estimates based on the growth factor of the preceding year. I plotted the curve directly against the A&R data in Figure 3 and Figure 4. After the hairs on the back of my neck settled down, I realized that this simple formula has some nice understandable properties. It essentially generates growth factors based solely on the maximum entropy dispersion in the underlying model. In other words, the "enigmatic" reserve growth has turned from a puzzle into a mathematical result resulting solely from simple stochastic effects. ![]() Figure 3: Fit to fractional yearly
growth of the A&R data
![]() Figure 4:
Fit to cumulative reserve growth of the A&R data. This was
calculated from the generating function in Figure 3. This correlates
well with the direct use of the reserve growth equation.
Plotting the same data against an Attanasi & Root chart in Figure 5, it lays cleanly on top of it, showing discrepancies only on some very old outlier data. A&R went through the rationale of discounting the outliers, but I consider all the data valuable, if it gets used in the context of a decent model. ![]() Figure 5:
Fit on top of the original A&R chart duplicated from Reference
1.
The blue line comes from the Dispersive Discovery reserve growth model.
Interestingly, with the limited data available, the reserve growth looks like it will continue on and eventually reach infinite values, but this becomes a mathematical impossibility if we integrate out the "thimble"-sized initial estimates. As a bottom-line, if we continue to make poor initial estimates for discoveries, we will continue to pay the price for acting surprised at the "huge" reserve growth we have. In other words, the USGS has pawned off a contrivance on us by making us believe that their trend lines went beyond mere empiricism. If you look back at the previous "model" that the USGS's Verma postulated2 based on the "modified Arrington" approach, you will realize that the trend line comes about purely from heuristic considerations. Their equation shows a fractional order power-law growth: CGF=1.7378(YSD)0.3152To top it off, this heuristic shows unlimited growth! Do you suppose that the USGS geologists figured out that by reserving judgment on the possibility of an asymptote, that they could pawn off a fast one on the public, and defer the reality for years to come? You have to ask yourself how these professionals get away with publishing stuff based on hacking and punting, that really has such a simple statistical and mathematical underlying foundation. I really find nothing complicated about the mathematics (even though it has taken me some time to arrive at my current state of understanding). I call this combination of using simple models and using straightforward calculus and probabilities a form of pragmathematics -- just something you do to understand the physical foundation for the data we observe. Referring again to the literature, you find hints that support the dispersive effects of accumulated reservoir estimates (note that they use the term dispersion). A graphic illustration of the very broad URA data dispersion that occurs when grouping fields across geologic types and geographic areas was provided by the National Petroleum Council (NPC) and is reproduced with minor modification in Figure FE5. ![]() I claim that this new dispersive discovery reserve growth model has the potential for filling in the back-dated discovery curves and providing better estimates of future production levels. I would recommend starting with the USA data and using Khebab's approach for regenerating a profile of un-back-dated discoveries and then applying the Oil Shock Model to estimate extrapolated production levels. It may take some time to sort out the mess, but we likely have all the pieces necessary to formulate a complete model-based projection. The actual enigma of reserve growth I think has to do with the cluelessness of the USGS and the secrecy and inscrutability of the oil industry. You would think they would have figured out the reserve growth puzzle long ago. I guess they thought that deferring the reality would surely provide us with infinite hope. The "How Did We Get Ourselves Into This Mess?" Epilogue A fraction of the population thinks that oil production remains a simple matter of turning the spigot clockwise to get more oil, and reserve growth a non-issue. And that raising the current reserve inventory becomes a conservative decision made entirely under the control of humans. Overestimating the size of a reservoir has significant financial advantages. You can attract huge initial investment capital if you exaggerate a claim. But this can also attract charlatans. So I agree with the SEC's decision to put the stops on that practice, with big fines for fraudulent claims. And thus the oil companies tried to make their reserve estimates as high as they could without overdoing it. But they still had no good ideas on how best to characterize their estimates (not smart? who knows?). Some people suggest that the industry just makes "conservative" decisions. Yet, I don't think that ambiguously-framed "conservative" decisions matches with well with what you can accomplish with a good reserve growth model. I would describe the industry's approach not "conservative" but "non-predictive" and "safe". I can point to lots of other engineering areas where through the routine process of characterization one can make equally conservative estimates, but they do an excellent job of predicting the asymptotic behavior with safety margins for any errors or noise that creeps in. As an example Andy Grove was the first to characterize silicon dioxide growth by evaluating simple models and thus began Intel. Getting oxide thickness correct could follow a process where someone checks the thickness every two minutes like they were watching a loaf of bread rise, but the technology and modeling has gone way beyond that now in Silicon Valley and China. Not so with the oil industry however; to the untrained eye it looks like they use the primitive trick of plunging a thermometer into the turkey roasting in the oven. This is safe but, jeez, how primitive! Bottom line, I believe the current industry estimates for reserve growth remain just as safe and non-predictive as a turkey thermometer, but that the underlying reality (having to do with the dispersion of searches through the volume of a reservoir) can vastly improve our educated guesses. This makes it potentially predictive if the industry had the balls to use a good validated model. The simple model I use for reserve growth is complementary to what Andy Grove did in the 60's. Unfortunately, I also don't think that petroleum engineers have any control over marketing decisions. It's possible that oil industry engineers knew about the characterization outlined here all along but were superceded by management's decisions. They used it in their own internal books and presented a "safe" facade for the outside world. Unfortunately, we turned the clock to a new century, and some nobodies on TOD have finally figured out the obvious that had stared at them and the USGS in the face for years. Journal References: 1 Attanasi, E.D., and Root, D.H., 1994, The enigma of oil and gas field growth: American Association of Petroleum Geologists Bulletin, v. 78, no. 3, p. 321-332. 2 Verma, M.K., 2003, Modified Arrington Method for Calculating Reserve Growth — A New Model for United States Oil and Gas Fields, U.S. Department of the Interior, U.S. Geological Survey Web References: |